Ep 11 All Else Equal with Jim Millstein: "Is Bankruptcy the End?"

00:28:47
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=-hVWYV5X0YY

Ringkasan

TLDRIn this episode of the All Else Equal Podcast, hosted by Jonathan Burke from Stanford University and Jules van Vincebergin from the University of Pennsylvania, the focus is on debunking misconceptions surrounding corporate bankruptcy. The key emphasis is on understanding that declaring bankruptcy doesn't necessarily imply the end of a company's existence; instead, it can be a strategic move for restructuring and continuation. The hosts use Hertz as a case study to explain how businesses can emerge from bankruptcy stronger if they're fundamentally healthy but over-leveraged. The discussion also delves into the nature of corporate bankruptcy being a shift in control from equity to debt holders, highlighting that it's often more about reorganization than liquidation. Furthermore, the episode explores the implications of a firm's debt-equity ratio and references the Modigliani and Miller Proposition, underscoring its importance in finance theory. In a case-specific illustration, the episode describes the General Motors bankruptcy, discussing the U.S. government’s intervention to prevent liquidation, thereby safeguarding millions of related jobs and stabilizing the auto industry during a tumultuous financial period. The role of professional advice and the costs associated with bankruptcy proceedings are discussed, alongside mentioning Jim Millstein's insight as a seasoned restructuring expert. Listeners are advised on careful consideration of economic incentives and pitfalls when contemplating the balance of debt versus equity, with an emphasis on the broader economic implications of major corporate bailouts and financial distress decisions.

Takeaways

  • πŸŽ™οΈ Bankruptcy misconceptions are common.
  • πŸ”„ Bankruptcy is often about restructuring, not liquidation.
  • πŸ’Ό Hertz emerged from bankruptcy despite initial struggles.
  • πŸ›‘οΈ The change of control is key in corporate bankruptcy.
  • πŸ“Š Modigliani and Miller's theory discusses debt-equity irrelevance.
  • πŸ“‰ GM's government bailout prevented massive job losses.
  • πŸ’° Debt financing impacts risk distribution.
  • βš–οΈ Considerations in bailout situations are complex.
  • πŸ’‘ Bankruptcy advice can be costly but necessary.
  • πŸ” Understanding financial distress is crucial for decisions.

Garis waktu

  • 00:00:00 - 00:05:00

    Jim Millstein continues, explaining the role of the government in GM's bankruptcy, acting as a key financer when no private investor stepped in. He argues that government intervention prevented a major economic fallout given the interconnected supply chains. Jonathan and Jules discuss the broader implications of such interventions and the complexity of determining when bailouts are justified.

  • 00:05:00 - 00:10:00

    Millstein highlights the minimal frequency of company liquidations versus reorganizations, thanks to Chapter 11 facilitating restructuring rather than shutdowns. He outlines the efficiency of this process relative to international standards and discusses the costs involved.

  • 00:10:00 - 00:15:00

    The conversation shifts to an analysis of bankruptcy costs, asserting that while absolute costs are significant, the relative costs to the company's value can be modest. Jules and Jonathan explore the flaws in some bailouts, stressing the importance of considering actual shutdown scenarios to understand true necessity.

  • 00:15:00 - 00:20:00

    Millstein explains how government bailouts sometimes act as support for entire industries, evidenced by GM's case where financial aid safeguarded not just the company but its extensive network of suppliers and associates. Therefore, evaluating bailout needs requires understanding the larger economic web involved.

  • 00:20:00 - 00:28:47

    The episode concludes with reflections on the complex decision-making during crises, like GM's, and the care needed to avoid All Else Equal mistakes when crafting hypothetical scenarios. This forms the basis for their next discussion on labor contracts and their role amid such corporate challenges.

Tampilkan lebih banyak

Peta Pikiran

Video Tanya Jawab

  • What is the main topic of this podcast episode?

    The episode discusses corporate bankruptcy and commonly held misconceptions about it.

  • Who are the hosts of the podcast?

    Jonathan Burke from Stanford University and Jules van Vincebergin from the University of Pennsylvania.

  • What's a common misconception about bankruptcy?

    A common misconception is that declaring bankruptcy means the firm will cease to exist, while it can often mean restructuring.

  • What example is used to illustrate the misconception about bankruptcy?

    The example of Hertz is used to illustrate the misconception that bankruptcy means the end of a firm.

  • What is the significance of bankruptcy in terms of business control?

    Bankruptcy is often a process of changing control from equity holders to debt holders, rather than ending operations.

  • Does the episode discuss any important financial theories?

    Yes, it discusses the Modigliani and Miller Proposition regarding the irrelevance of a firm's debt-equity ratio in a frictionless world.

  • What notable company's bankruptcy is discussed in the episode?

    The episode discusses the bankruptcy of General Motors (GM) and the government's role in its restructuring.

  • Why did GM need a bailout during its bankruptcy?

    The U.S. government intervened to prevent shut down due to the potential massive job losses and disruption to the supply chain it would have caused.

  • What role did Jim Millstein play in the context of the GM bailout?

    Jim Millstein was the Chief Restructuring Officer at the U.S. Department of the Treasury and was involved in overseeing GM's restructuring.

  • What is one consequence of the way companies finance with debt according to the episode?

    One consequence is the potential risk shift from the firm to employees due to harder long-term contract negotiations with significant debt.

Lihat lebih banyak ringkasan video

Dapatkan akses instan ke ringkasan video YouTube gratis yang didukung oleh AI!
Teks
en
Gulir Otomatis:
  • 00:00:00
    [MUSIC]
  • 00:00:07
    Hi, I'm Jonathan Burke, Professor
  • 00:00:09
    of Finance in the Graduate School
  • 00:00:11
    of Business at Stanford university.
  • 00:00:13
    >> And I'm Jules van Vincebergin,
  • 00:00:15
    a Finance Professor
  • 00:00:16
    at the Wharton School of
  • 00:00:17
    the University of Pennsylvania.
  • 00:00:19
    >> And this is
  • 00:00:20
    the All Else Equal Podcast.
  • 00:00:24
    Welcome back, everybody.
  • 00:00:26
    Before we get started today I just
  • 00:00:27
    want to make a call out to our
  • 00:00:29
    listeners and thank them for
  • 00:00:30
    listening, especially the listeners
  • 00:00:32
    who subscribed.
  • 00:00:33
    It's really amazing to see
  • 00:00:35
    how many subscribers they are and
  • 00:00:37
    it's really motivating in terms of
  • 00:00:39
    what we're doing here.
  • 00:00:41
    >> Today we're going to talk about
  • 00:00:42
    corporate bankruptcy.
  • 00:00:44
    And the All Else Equal
  • 00:00:45
    mistakes we're going to talk about
  • 00:00:47
    is the assumption that the act of
  • 00:00:48
    declaring bankruptcy itself is
  • 00:00:50
    precipitating the end of the firm.
  • 00:00:53
    That is, the bankruptcy decision
  • 00:00:54
    itself is consequent in ending
  • 00:00:56
    the firm's existence.
  • 00:00:57
    And I think that's a pretty common
  • 00:00:58
    assumption, Jonathan.
  • 00:00:59
    Usually when we see that a firm
  • 00:01:01
    declares bankruptcy people think,
  • 00:01:02
    that's the end of it.
  • 00:01:04
    >> Yeah, as seemingly
  • 00:01:05
    obvious as this assumption is,
  • 00:01:07
    it's a mistake, okay?
  • 00:01:09
    So let's think about that.
  • 00:01:11
    There are two reasons a firm would
  • 00:01:12
    enter bankruptcy.
  • 00:01:13
    One reason is the underlying
  • 00:01:15
    business is failing.
  • 00:01:16
    And so I think that happens when
  • 00:01:18
    the cost of continuing the business
  • 00:01:20
    is higher than what it actually
  • 00:01:22
    brings in in revenues.
  • 00:01:23
    >> Exactly.
  • 00:01:24
    >> Or alternatively, underlying
  • 00:01:26
    business is perfectly fine, but
  • 00:01:28
    the firm just has too much debt.
  • 00:01:30
    So one example that I think
  • 00:01:31
    is interesting to discuss
  • 00:01:33
    here is Hertz, right?
  • 00:01:34
    So Hertz doing the COVID
  • 00:01:36
    crisis had a pretty rough time, and
  • 00:01:38
    at some point they decided
  • 00:01:39
    to declare bankruptcy.
  • 00:01:41
    And then 12 months later,
  • 00:01:43
    suddenly Hertz has emerged
  • 00:01:44
    out of bankruptcy.
  • 00:01:46
    So I think that is a clear
  • 00:01:47
    indication that if we have to
  • 00:01:49
    choose between the two reasons for
  • 00:01:50
    bankruptcy, one was the business is
  • 00:01:52
    failing, the other one was they
  • 00:01:53
    just had too much debt and they had
  • 00:01:55
    to somehow reorganize that.
  • 00:01:57
    I think the second is the more
  • 00:01:58
    plausible explanation.
  • 00:01:59
    >> Well, but
  • 00:02:00
    the other thing to remember is,
  • 00:02:02
    even during the bankruptcy,
  • 00:02:03
    you could still rent Hertz cars.
  • 00:02:05
    In fact, from a consumer's
  • 00:02:07
    perspective, they didn't even
  • 00:02:08
    know about the bankruptcy.
  • 00:02:09
    Hertz looked just like Avis.
  • 00:02:11
    Why don't we talk about how
  • 00:02:13
    bankruptcy came to be?
  • 00:02:14
    Originally when you didn't pay your
  • 00:02:16
    debts back, they put you in prison,
  • 00:02:18
    and we as a society realized there
  • 00:02:19
    were some moral issues with that.
  • 00:02:21
    And so we came up with bankruptcy
  • 00:02:23
    law, which essentially was
  • 00:02:25
    a way for debtors to collect as
  • 00:02:27
    much as they could.
  • 00:02:28
    And obviously you can't put
  • 00:02:29
    a corporation in prison.
  • 00:02:30
    So in that sense,
  • 00:02:32
    corporate bankruptcy is just
  • 00:02:34
    an orderly process for the debtors
  • 00:02:37
    to collect as much as they can.
  • 00:02:40
    They're obviously not going to be
  • 00:02:41
    fully paid back, otherwise wouldn't
  • 00:02:43
    have a bankruptcy, but they're
  • 00:02:44
    going to get as much as they can.
  • 00:02:45
    >> And so the debt holders
  • 00:02:46
    have a very clear choice to make.
  • 00:02:48
    Whenever a firm is declaring
  • 00:02:49
    bankruptcy, given the fact that
  • 00:02:51
    the debt holders want to get back
  • 00:02:53
    as much as they can, how will they
  • 00:02:55
    get back as much as they can?
  • 00:02:56
    On the one hand they can say,
  • 00:02:58
    let's just sell off every piece
  • 00:03:00
    of property that Hertz has.
  • 00:03:01
    Let's sell off all the cars,
  • 00:03:03
    that sell off all the real estate,
  • 00:03:04
    and let's see how much money we
  • 00:03:06
    can recoup that way.
  • 00:03:07
    The alternative for the debt
  • 00:03:09
    holders is to say, you know what,
  • 00:03:11
    actually Hertz is worth more to us
  • 00:03:13
    by just continuing operating it and
  • 00:03:15
    try to recoup as much money as we
  • 00:03:17
    can that way, right.?
  • 00:03:18
    >> Right, so really what bankruptcy
  • 00:03:21
    is in a corporate situation is
  • 00:03:23
    simply a change of control.
  • 00:03:25
    Before the bankruptcy, the equity
  • 00:03:28
    holders controlled the firm, or the
  • 00:03:30
    shareholders controlled the firm.
  • 00:03:33
    After the bankruptcy,
  • 00:03:34
    the shareholders get nothing and
  • 00:03:36
    the debt holders get all their
  • 00:03:38
    assets, so they take control of
  • 00:03:39
    the firm and they make decision to
  • 00:03:41
    continue operations or
  • 00:03:42
    shut the firm down, but the debtors
  • 00:03:44
    will make that decision.
  • 00:03:46
    So anybody who has lent money to
  • 00:03:48
    the firm gets control of the firm.
  • 00:03:50
    So the really insightful thing to
  • 00:03:53
    realize is all
  • 00:03:54
    a corporate bankruptcy is is
  • 00:03:57
    a change of control.
  • 00:03:58
    >> So now let's generalize this
  • 00:04:01
    a bit and just think about two
  • 00:04:02
    identical firms.
  • 00:04:05
    The firms operate exactly the same
  • 00:04:06
    type of business,
  • 00:04:07
    they sell the same products,
  • 00:04:08
    they have the same employees,
  • 00:04:10
    everything is the same.
  • 00:04:11
    The only thing that's different
  • 00:04:12
    between these two firms is
  • 00:04:14
    how much debt they have.
  • 00:04:15
    Now the question is,
  • 00:04:16
    is the decision to continue
  • 00:04:18
    operating the business,
  • 00:04:20
    is that in any way dependent on how
  • 00:04:22
    much debt we have, okay?
  • 00:04:24
    >> Let's assume that the firm with
  • 00:04:27
    debt declares bankruptcy, but
  • 00:04:30
    assume the firm is healthy,
  • 00:04:32
    what's going to happen?
  • 00:04:34
    >> Well, in that case,
  • 00:04:35
    if the business model is fine, and
  • 00:04:37
    it's more profitable to continue
  • 00:04:38
    operating the firm compared to
  • 00:04:40
    shutting it down,
  • 00:04:40
    he'll just continue.
  • 00:04:42
    >> Now the all equity
  • 00:04:42
    firm obviously can't declare
  • 00:04:44
    bankruptcy because there's no debt
  • 00:04:45
    in that firm, but it's identical,
  • 00:04:47
    it will also continue operating.
  • 00:04:49
    So both firms will
  • 00:04:50
    continue operating.
  • 00:04:51
    Okay, let's take the alternative.
  • 00:04:53
    >> So now we're looking at a firm
  • 00:04:55
    where the cost of continuing
  • 00:04:56
    operation is higher than
  • 00:04:57
    the revenue would brings in.
  • 00:04:59
    So from a business decision making
  • 00:05:01
    point of view, the better decision
  • 00:05:03
    is to shut down the firm.
  • 00:05:04
    >> So when the debt holders take
  • 00:05:06
    possession of the firm,
  • 00:05:07
    what are they going to do?
  • 00:05:09
    They're going to
  • 00:05:09
    liquidate the firm.
  • 00:05:11
    But obviously the same must be true
  • 00:05:13
    of the all equity firm.
  • 00:05:15
    It's not a good business decision
  • 00:05:17
    of that firm to keep operating.
  • 00:05:18
    We just said,
  • 00:05:19
    you're better off shutting it
  • 00:05:21
    down than keep operating.
  • 00:05:22
    So the equity holders in that
  • 00:05:24
    firm will also shut it down.
  • 00:05:26
    And so yet again,
  • 00:05:27
    both firms make the same decision.
  • 00:05:30
    >> So we've just proven
  • 00:05:31
    the point where we started off
  • 00:05:32
    the discussion.
  • 00:05:33
    And that is the act of declaring
  • 00:05:35
    bankruptcy itself has no impact on
  • 00:05:37
    the question of whether it's a good
  • 00:05:39
    business decision to keep the firm
  • 00:05:41
    operating or not.
  • 00:05:43
    So now the question is,
  • 00:05:44
    can we generalize this argument if
  • 00:05:46
    the way that the firm is financed
  • 00:05:47
    with debt and equity and
  • 00:05:49
    in what ratio doesn't matter for
  • 00:05:50
    this important business decision,
  • 00:05:52
    does it matter for
  • 00:05:53
    any other business decision that
  • 00:05:54
    we're making inside the firm?
  • 00:05:56
    >> And the answer is no,
  • 00:05:58
    it doesn't matter,
  • 00:05:59
    using the same intuition.
  • 00:06:01
    Financial economists call this the
  • 00:06:03
    Modigliani and Miller Proposition,
  • 00:06:05
    named after Modigliani and
  • 00:06:07
    Miller, who won the Nobel Prize for
  • 00:06:09
    pointing it out.
  • 00:06:10
    Ironically, they were not the first
  • 00:06:12
    people to derive it.
  • 00:06:13
    The first person to
  • 00:06:14
    have this important
  • 00:06:15
    insight was John Burr Williams, and
  • 00:06:18
    I think the Nobel Prize Committee
  • 00:06:20
    erred in not giving the Nobel Prize
  • 00:06:22
    to John Burr Williams, when they
  • 00:06:24
    gave it to Modigliani Miller.
  • 00:06:26
    >> Isn't there some funny joke
  • 00:06:27
    about this, about propositions?
  • 00:06:29
    >> Yes, my good friend
  • 00:06:31
    Mark Rubinstein used to
  • 00:06:32
    say if a proposition is named
  • 00:06:34
    after somebody,
  • 00:06:35
    it almost certainly means they were
  • 00:06:37
    not the first people to derive it.
  • 00:06:40
    >> So let's use John Burr Williams'
  • 00:06:41
    argument to understand it better.
  • 00:06:44
    The way that he went about
  • 00:06:45
    it was as follows.
  • 00:06:45
    He said, suppose that there's only
  • 00:06:48
    one person who owns both the equity
  • 00:06:50
    and the debt of the firm.
  • 00:06:53
    Now what could it possibly matter
  • 00:06:55
    for the business decision how
  • 00:06:57
    to proceed in what ratio that
  • 00:06:59
    person holds both those pieces.
  • 00:07:01
    >> In other words, it's just
  • 00:07:03
    relabeling, that person has all
  • 00:07:05
    the cash flows the firm generates.
  • 00:07:07
    So you can label one as debt and
  • 00:07:08
    equity, but the total cash flows
  • 00:07:10
    are the same, and so
  • 00:07:11
    that person isn't going to care.
  • 00:07:13
    And that's how John Burr Williams
  • 00:07:15
    derived the very important insight
  • 00:07:18
    that how the firm finances itself
  • 00:07:20
    doesn't affect the underlying
  • 00:07:23
    business model of the firm.
  • 00:07:25
    >> And so there is a very important
  • 00:07:27
    all else equal mistake that follows
  • 00:07:29
    from this wrong way of thinking
  • 00:07:31
    about the debt equity ratio.
  • 00:07:33
    And that is that many people,
  • 00:07:35
    often bankers, claim that you
  • 00:07:37
    should always finance your firm
  • 00:07:40
    with debt because they say debt is
  • 00:07:42
    cheaper because she can get it at
  • 00:07:44
    a lower rate than having to entice
  • 00:07:47
    equity holders to invest with you.
  • 00:07:49
    And for that reason, you should
  • 00:07:51
    always finance your firm with debt.
  • 00:07:53
    >> And that's an all else equal
  • 00:07:55
    mistake because what it's ignoring
  • 00:07:57
    is the reason debt has a lower.
  • 00:08:00
    Return is because it's less risky.
  • 00:08:02
    Equity is more risky than debt and
  • 00:08:04
    has a higher return.
  • 00:08:05
    It's no cheaper,
  • 00:08:06
    it's just your investors are taking
  • 00:08:08
    on different risks.
  • 00:08:10
    >> And in fact, if as a firm you
  • 00:08:12
    take on more debts, you are
  • 00:08:13
    actually making the equity riskier.
  • 00:08:16
    Because you will have to pay
  • 00:08:17
    the debt holders back first before
  • 00:08:19
    the equity holders get anything.
  • 00:08:20
    >> Exactly, the equity of an all
  • 00:08:22
    equity firm is less risky than
  • 00:08:24
    the equity of a firm with debt.
  • 00:08:26
    But the overall riskiness of
  • 00:08:28
    the firm is the same and
  • 00:08:30
    Berwyn said that.
  • 00:08:31
    Look, if I have an all equity firm
  • 00:08:33
    that's going to have a certain
  • 00:08:34
    level of risk, if I'm the single
  • 00:08:36
    investor in that firm or if
  • 00:08:38
    I've a firm with debt and equity,
  • 00:08:40
    certainly my debt and equity is
  • 00:08:41
    going to have different risks.
  • 00:08:43
    But I'm getting the same cash flows
  • 00:08:46
    so my overall risk is the same as
  • 00:08:48
    it is for the all equity firm.
  • 00:08:50
    >> And now finally,
  • 00:08:50
    let's circle back to the very
  • 00:08:52
    beginning of our discussion.
  • 00:08:53
    In making the mistake of equating
  • 00:08:55
    bankruptcy with liquidation,
  • 00:08:56
    people often make the mistake of
  • 00:08:58
    subsidizing firms when there's no
  • 00:09:00
    reason for it.
  • 00:09:01
    We've heard a lot about when firms
  • 00:09:03
    get in trouble,
  • 00:09:04
    we need to bail them out.
  • 00:09:06
    But let's think a little carefully
  • 00:09:08
    about what that bailing out
  • 00:09:09
    actually implies.
  • 00:09:11
    >> Well, when would be a situation
  • 00:09:12
    where you've to bail out a firm?
  • 00:09:13
    Because as we discussed, if
  • 00:09:15
    the firm is a good firm to operate,
  • 00:09:17
    the debt holders will
  • 00:09:18
    keep operating it, so
  • 00:09:20
    there's no reason to bail it out.
  • 00:09:22
    So the only time you have to
  • 00:09:23
    bail it out is if the firm doesn't
  • 00:09:25
    make sense to operate.
  • 00:09:26
    And normally when we say we have
  • 00:09:28
    firms that don't make sense to
  • 00:09:29
    operate, the optimal thing is to
  • 00:09:31
    shut them down.
  • 00:09:32
    The only condition under which
  • 00:09:34
    you wouldn't want to shut the firm
  • 00:09:36
    down is there some externality for
  • 00:09:38
    the firm operating.
  • 00:09:39
    >> So for example, there could be
  • 00:09:41
    suppliers of the firm or
  • 00:09:42
    other parties that are connected to
  • 00:09:44
    the firm.
  • 00:09:45
    In the case of General Motors,
  • 00:09:46
    I think this argument was made
  • 00:09:48
    quite forcibly that too many people
  • 00:09:50
    dependent on General Motors to be
  • 00:09:51
    couldn't let it fail and the
  • 00:09:53
    externalities were large enough.
  • 00:09:55
    >> But the problem of course Jules
  • 00:09:57
    is, if I am the debt holder I would
  • 00:09:59
    like to subsidize.
  • 00:10:00
    I could easily argue that I'm going
  • 00:10:03
    to shut the firm down if
  • 00:10:04
    the subsidy didn't exist,
  • 00:10:06
    knowing full well that in fact that
  • 00:10:08
    wouldn't be my case.
  • 00:10:10
    So we have to be very careful when
  • 00:10:12
    debt holders announce or
  • 00:10:13
    threaten to shut the firm down.
  • 00:10:15
    We have to actually make sure that
  • 00:10:17
    that's what they're going to do.
  • 00:10:18
    >> Yeah, because anybody likes to
  • 00:10:20
    receive a subsidy if he can.
  • 00:10:22
    So Jonathan, one last thing to
  • 00:10:24
    discuss then though is, when
  • 00:10:26
    you look at the surveys of CFOs and
  • 00:10:28
    you ask CFOs what is the most
  • 00:10:31
    important part of your job?
  • 00:10:33
    They do indicate that how much debt
  • 00:10:35
    and equity financing they should
  • 00:10:37
    use is at the top of that list.
  • 00:10:39
    So what are we missing?
  • 00:10:41
    >> Well, I think this will we
  • 00:10:42
    talked about he was pretty
  • 00:10:44
    simplistic and
  • 00:10:45
    then in the real world
  • 00:10:46
    the decisions are more complicated.
  • 00:10:49
    We spoke about one
  • 00:10:49
    friction already,
  • 00:10:51
    which is the externalities, right?
  • 00:10:53
    The first kind of externalities,
  • 00:10:54
    but there are other
  • 00:10:55
    frictions because obviously
  • 00:10:57
    bankruptcies cost the process.
  • 00:10:59
    You have to hire lawyers, and
  • 00:11:01
    the other thing about bankruptcy is
  • 00:11:03
    contracts don't survive.
  • 00:11:05
    So not just the debt contract, you
  • 00:11:06
    could have other contracts in the
  • 00:11:08
    firm that don't survive bankruptcy.
  • 00:11:09
    So it could be difficult to
  • 00:11:11
    write contracts if the firm
  • 00:11:13
    has a lot of debt.
  • 00:11:14
    Because the person on the other
  • 00:11:16
    side of the contract anticipates if
  • 00:11:17
    there's a chance of bankruptcy and
  • 00:11:19
    this contract might not be honored.
  • 00:11:21
    >> Like the labor contract?
  • 00:11:22
    >> Exactly, there's a good example,
  • 00:11:24
    the labor contract.
  • 00:11:25
    So workers inferred in a lot of
  • 00:11:27
    debt might worry that a labor
  • 00:11:28
    contract that says they can't be
  • 00:11:31
    fired would be violated in the case
  • 00:11:33
    of bankruptcy.
  • 00:11:34
    >> And then there is another
  • 00:11:35
    very important friction and
  • 00:11:37
    that friction is, and we've
  • 00:11:38
    discussed this friction before.
  • 00:11:40
    Financing with debt has a benefit
  • 00:11:42
    because interest payments are tax
  • 00:11:44
    deductible.
  • 00:11:44
    Because your tax bill is computed
  • 00:11:46
    on the after interest payment
  • 00:11:48
    profits not the before interest
  • 00:11:50
    payment profits.
  • 00:11:51
    And so by financing your firm
  • 00:11:53
    more with debts,
  • 00:11:54
    you can keep more of the money for
  • 00:11:56
    the stakeholders in the firm and
  • 00:11:58
    not give it to the government.
  • 00:12:00
    And that increases the value of
  • 00:12:01
    the firm but also sometimes we call
  • 00:12:03
    the tax shield.
  • 00:12:04
    >> And that is one of my big
  • 00:12:07
    concerns about how we tax.
  • 00:12:09
    What effectively the government's
  • 00:12:12
    doing is encouraging firms to hold
  • 00:12:14
    more debt.
  • 00:12:15
    If the firm has more debt,
  • 00:12:16
    it's harder to write long-term
  • 00:12:19
    contracts.
  • 00:12:19
    So it's harder for the employees to
  • 00:12:22
    write a contract with a firm that
  • 00:12:23
    gives them job security.
  • 00:12:25
    Now, job security is a pretty
  • 00:12:26
    useful thing.
  • 00:12:27
    And we're moving risk
  • 00:12:28
    from the employee to the firm,
  • 00:12:30
    which is the optimal thing to do.
  • 00:12:32
    So making their contract harder to
  • 00:12:35
    write makes employees harder to
  • 00:12:37
    hire.
  • 00:12:38
    And it's overall bad I think for
  • 00:12:40
    the economy as a whole because
  • 00:12:41
    having that insurance is good for
  • 00:12:43
    everybody.
  • 00:12:44
    >> Agreed.
  • 00:12:45
    So let's summarize.
  • 00:12:46
    We started off with in a world
  • 00:12:48
    without these frictions that we
  • 00:12:50
    discussed at the end,
  • 00:12:51
    the trade off between how much debt
  • 00:12:53
    and equity you should hold,
  • 00:12:55
    there isn't much there.
  • 00:12:57
    It doesn't really matter how you
  • 00:12:58
    finance yourself whether it's with
  • 00:12:59
    equity or debt.
  • 00:13:00
    We illustrated this with a very
  • 00:13:01
    simple decision to make,
  • 00:13:03
    which was the decision to continue
  • 00:13:05
    operating or not.
  • 00:13:06
    And we concluded that for that
  • 00:13:07
    business decision it didn't matter
  • 00:13:09
    how you financed yourself and
  • 00:13:10
    came been generalized.
  • 00:13:11
    Adam came to the conclusion that
  • 00:13:13
    for any business decision in this
  • 00:13:14
    frictionless world, it wouldn't
  • 00:13:16
    matter how you financed yourself.
  • 00:13:18
    But to make it more nuanced at the
  • 00:13:19
    end, I do think we need to include
  • 00:13:21
    these frictions in the discussion.
  • 00:13:23
    How important are these frictions,
  • 00:13:24
    how important are these
  • 00:13:25
    labor contracts?
  • 00:13:26
    How valuable is the fact that debt
  • 00:13:28
    is text deductible, how costly is
  • 00:13:30
    the bankruptcy process for
  • 00:13:31
    everybody involved?
  • 00:13:33
    >> That's a very important
  • 00:13:34
    insight Jules.
  • 00:13:35
    In other words, it is important
  • 00:13:37
    when people claim that the level
  • 00:13:40
    of debt matters, that they also
  • 00:13:42
    explain what friction is causing it
  • 00:13:45
    to matter.
  • 00:13:46
    If they don't explain what
  • 00:13:48
    friction is causing it to matter,
  • 00:13:49
    I'm highly suspicious that in fact
  • 00:13:51
    they want to get something out of
  • 00:13:52
    you and they're going to make
  • 00:13:54
    a blecious argument to do that.
  • 00:13:55
    >> And just saying the rate of
  • 00:13:57
    return on debt is lower than
  • 00:13:58
    the rate you have to pay to equity
  • 00:14:00
    holders to entice them to invest,
  • 00:14:02
    that argument on its own doesn't
  • 00:14:04
    specify friction, and for
  • 00:14:05
    that reason is not a useful
  • 00:14:07
    argument to use.
  • 00:14:08
    >> Okay, Jules, so I think now it's
  • 00:14:09
    time to introduce our guest.
  • 00:14:11
    >> We're very happy to have our
  • 00:14:13
    guest today, Jim Millstein.
  • 00:14:15
    Jim is the Co-Chairman of
  • 00:14:17
    Guggenheim Securities, investment
  • 00:14:18
    banking in capital markets business
  • 00:14:20
    of Guggenheim Partners, a global
  • 00:14:22
    investment and advisory firm.
  • 00:14:23
    From 2009 to 2011, Jim was
  • 00:14:25
    the Chief Restructuring Officer at
  • 00:14:27
    the US Department of the Treasury
  • 00:14:29
    when the Obama administration
  • 00:14:31
    bailed out General Motors.
  • 00:14:32
    In that role he was also
  • 00:14:34
    responsible for oversight and
  • 00:14:35
    management of the department's
  • 00:14:37
    largest investments
  • 00:14:38
    in the financial sector and was
  • 00:14:40
    the principal architect of AIG's
  • 00:14:41
    restructuring and recapitalization.
  • 00:14:44
    Prior to joining the treasury,
  • 00:14:45
    Jim served as Global Co-Head of
  • 00:14:47
    Corporate Restructuring at
  • 00:14:48
    Lazard from 2000 to 2008.
  • 00:14:50
    An authority represented the United
  • 00:14:52
    Auto Workers in connection with the
  • 00:14:54
    restructuring of their contractual
  • 00:14:57
    relations with GM, Ford,
  • 00:14:58
    and Chrysler from 2005 to 2007.
  • 00:15:01
    Jim welcome to the show.
  • 00:15:03
    >> Nice to be here, thanks for
  • 00:15:04
    having me.
  • 00:15:05
    >> So Jim you spent your whole
  • 00:15:07
    career dealing with firms in
  • 00:15:09
    bankruptcy.
  • 00:15:10
    Let me ask you a question
  • 00:15:11
    just as a summary of all
  • 00:15:12
    the bankruptcies you've dealt with.
  • 00:15:14
    What fraction of the time was
  • 00:15:16
    the end result liquidation versus
  • 00:15:18
    a transfer of control?
  • 00:15:20
    >> I've probably worked on 400
  • 00:15:21
    different restructurings over
  • 00:15:23
    the course of the last 42 years
  • 00:15:25
    doing this kind of work.
  • 00:15:26
    And I would say really only twice
  • 00:15:29
    over that period has it resulted in
  • 00:15:32
    a liquidation.
  • 00:15:34
    The chapter 11 of
  • 00:15:35
    the United States Bankruptcy Code
  • 00:15:37
    was really designed to facilitate
  • 00:15:39
    the reorganization of companies
  • 00:15:40
    rather than their liquidation.
  • 00:15:42
    Liquidation value to use legally
  • 00:15:45
    as a standard by which plans of
  • 00:15:48
    reorganization are judged.
  • 00:15:50
    But it is a very rare bankruptcy
  • 00:15:52
    that ends up liquidated.
  • 00:15:54
    >> So Jim, obviously the transfer
  • 00:15:56
    of control from equity holders to
  • 00:15:58
    debt holders is not simple,
  • 00:16:00
    it involve costs.
  • 00:16:01
    What do you think the major costs
  • 00:16:03
    are and how important are they in
  • 00:16:06
    the bigger picture
  • 00:16:07
    of the company as a whole?
  • 00:16:09
    >> Well, the friction costs of all
  • 00:16:11
    the professionals involved in
  • 00:16:13
    a large case,
  • 00:16:14
    those can be quite considerable.
  • 00:16:16
    But the bankruptcy courts,
  • 00:16:17
    the judges themselves have gotten
  • 00:16:19
    relatively good at policing
  • 00:16:21
    the running up of
  • 00:16:22
    unnecessary fees and expenses.
  • 00:16:24
    But the truth is that in a large
  • 00:16:27
    bankruptcy, all of the parties
  • 00:16:30
    retain specialized advisors.
  • 00:16:32
    And so you can have a conference
  • 00:16:35
    goal or a court hearing or
  • 00:16:36
    a negotiation session.
  • 00:16:38
    And when you look around,
  • 00:16:40
    there are 100 people billing their
  • 00:16:43
    time to a creditor,
  • 00:16:44
    or in many cases,
  • 00:16:45
    to the estate itself.
  • 00:16:47
    And so those friction costs
  • 00:16:49
    are real.
  • 00:16:51
    >> Okay, the costs are substantial
  • 00:16:53
    in absolute terms.
  • 00:16:54
    But in relative terms versus
  • 00:16:55
    the value of the corporation,
  • 00:16:57
    it's still not more than in
  • 00:16:59
    the percentage terms.
  • 00:17:00
    One, two, three,
  • 00:17:01
    four percent of the value of
  • 00:17:03
    the corporation of all the costs
  • 00:17:05
    associated with the bankruptcy, or
  • 00:17:07
    am I wrong about that?
  • 00:17:08
    >> It's very hard to give a rule of
  • 00:17:11
    thumb.
  • 00:17:12
    There are cases such as the Caesars
  • 00:17:14
    bankruptcy on which I worked where
  • 00:17:17
    the professional fees were running
  • 00:17:19
    a couple of $100 million a year.
  • 00:17:22
    But at the end of the day,
  • 00:17:24
    the estate, the reorganized company
  • 00:17:26
    was worth $30 billion.
  • 00:17:28
    So would you pay $200 million
  • 00:17:30
    to right size the balance sheet of
  • 00:17:32
    a company that ultimately was worth
  • 00:17:34
    $30 billion?
  • 00:17:35
    Yeah, you would.
  • 00:17:37
    Would you pay $3 million to right
  • 00:17:39
    size the balance sheet of a company
  • 00:17:42
    ultimately worth $50 million?
  • 00:17:44
    You'd be very careful in
  • 00:17:46
    supervising the professionals
  • 00:17:49
    involved in that size of case to
  • 00:17:51
    keep the fees down.
  • 00:17:54
    >> So, Jim, on that note,
  • 00:17:55
    do you think the bankruptcy process
  • 00:17:57
    is the most efficient way to handle
  • 00:18:00
    financial distress?
  • 00:18:01
    Or do you think there's
  • 00:18:02
    a lot of room for improvement?
  • 00:18:04
    >> Look, there's always room for
  • 00:18:05
    improvement.
  • 00:18:06
    I sat on a commission organized by
  • 00:18:08
    the American Bankruptcy Institute
  • 00:18:09
    called at the Commission to
  • 00:18:11
    Study Reform of Chapter 11.
  • 00:18:12
    And we came up with probably a 400
  • 00:18:14
    page tome that had a series
  • 00:18:16
    of recommendations to improve
  • 00:18:18
    the process.
  • 00:18:19
    But when you compare the legal
  • 00:18:21
    framework for
  • 00:18:21
    reorganizations applicable iin
  • 00:18:24
    the United States to those
  • 00:18:25
    available in other jurisdictions,
  • 00:18:27
    really Chapter 11 is probably
  • 00:18:29
    the most efficient reorganization
  • 00:18:32
    statute in the world.
  • 00:18:33
    Indeed, over the course of my
  • 00:18:35
    career over the last 40 years,
  • 00:18:38
    all of the so-called developed
  • 00:18:40
    countries and
  • 00:18:41
    many of the developing countries
  • 00:18:43
    have modernized their bankruptcy
  • 00:18:46
    statutes really after Chapter 11.
  • 00:18:49
    Because it has been
  • 00:18:50
    such a successful form in
  • 00:18:52
    which to salvage the valuable bits
  • 00:18:55
    of an operating business and
  • 00:18:57
    allow it to reorganize.
  • 00:18:59
    >> Could you comment a bit on
  • 00:19:01
    how you view bailouts?
  • 00:19:02
    So, for example,
  • 00:19:03
    the General Motors bankruptcy,
  • 00:19:05
    I think a lot of academics viewed
  • 00:19:07
    that as a watershed event in
  • 00:19:08
    the sense that the government
  • 00:19:10
    bailed out General Motors.
  • 00:19:12
    But absent that government support,
  • 00:19:14
    don't you think the company would
  • 00:19:15
    have been reorganized anyway?
  • 00:19:17
    >> Actually, I think most people
  • 00:19:19
    who are not bankruptcy
  • 00:19:20
    professionals don't understand what
  • 00:19:23
    happened in the GM bankruptcy.
  • 00:19:25
    The government really behaved
  • 00:19:27
    like an aggressive activist vulture
  • 00:19:30
    fund, and it employed tactics very
  • 00:19:32
    similar to those that the most
  • 00:19:34
    sophisticated investors
  • 00:19:36
    in Chapter 11 employ to facilitate
  • 00:19:38
    the reorganization of the company.
  • 00:19:40
    Do I think GM would have
  • 00:19:41
    survived without
  • 00:19:42
    the government's intervention?
  • 00:19:44
    Not at that time,
  • 00:19:45
    it had a severe run on
  • 00:19:46
    the liquidity available to it, and
  • 00:19:49
    it would have had to shut down.
  • 00:19:51
    Now, one of the reasons I think
  • 00:19:53
    most people don't understand and
  • 00:19:56
    unfairly criticized the government
  • 00:19:58
    and its capacity a dip lender in
  • 00:20:01
    that proceeding is that
  • 00:20:02
    the government went to the existing
  • 00:20:05
    secured creditors of GM,
  • 00:20:07
    the people first in line to receive
  • 00:20:09
    the value of GM's assets.
  • 00:20:11
    And said,
  • 00:20:12
    hey, if you guys want to put up
  • 00:20:15
    the dip, if you want to finance
  • 00:20:17
    it in Chapter 11,
  • 00:20:19
    please go right ahead.
  • 00:20:21
    And it was only after those
  • 00:20:23
    creditors who really were entitled
  • 00:20:25
    to whatever the value of GM was
  • 00:20:27
    because they had liens on virtually
  • 00:20:30
    all of its assets.
  • 00:20:31
    It was only after those creditors
  • 00:20:33
    declined the offer to
  • 00:20:35
    provide financing.
  • 00:20:37
    Now, remember,
  • 00:20:38
    when this all occurred,
  • 00:20:39
    this was in January of 2009,
  • 00:20:41
    in the middle, probably the deepest
  • 00:20:44
    point in the financial crisis.
  • 00:20:45
    And in the same way that
  • 00:20:47
    the federal government was a lender
  • 00:20:49
    of last resort through the fed,
  • 00:20:51
    through the FDIC,
  • 00:20:52
    through the Treasury Department to
  • 00:20:55
    the financial industry.
  • 00:20:56
    It turned out that the most
  • 00:20:58
    sophisticated distressed and
  • 00:21:00
    special situation investors who
  • 00:21:02
    had piled into GM secured debt were
  • 00:21:04
    unwilling to step up at that
  • 00:21:06
    moment of crisis and keep GM alive.
  • 00:21:08
    And so in order to save the jobs,
  • 00:21:10
    in order to keep the factories
  • 00:21:12
    running, in order to ensure that
  • 00:21:14
    the largest domestic automobile
  • 00:21:16
    manufacturer didn't shut down in
  • 00:21:19
    the middle of the crisis,
  • 00:21:20
    the government was forced
  • 00:21:22
    to step in where private investors
  • 00:21:24
    refused to tread.
  • 00:21:26
    >> How do you know those investors
  • 00:21:28
    weren't even more sophisticated,
  • 00:21:31
    knowing full well that the Obama
  • 00:21:33
    administration wasn't going to let
  • 00:21:36
    GM fail?
  • 00:21:37
    And so they didn't
  • 00:21:38
    provide the financing because
  • 00:21:40
    they anticipated the bailout.
  • 00:21:43
    >> Yes, well, the reason academics
  • 00:21:45
    have swirled around this and tried
  • 00:21:48
    to comment on it is because those
  • 00:21:50
    investors made a huge stink when
  • 00:21:52
    the government then after becoming
  • 00:21:55
    the dip lender sought to get the
  • 00:21:57
    company quickly out of bankruptcy.
  • 00:22:00
    As many of them would have done in
  • 00:22:02
    a similar position had they made
  • 00:22:05
    the dip loan.
  • 00:22:06
    Because a company as complex as
  • 00:22:08
    GM with international operations, I
  • 00:22:11
    mean, really very complicated, very
  • 00:22:14
    hard to run international company
  • 00:22:16
    in one bankruptcy jurisdiction.
  • 00:22:19
    So GM's assets were sold as a going
  • 00:22:21
    concern to a newly formed entity,
  • 00:22:23
    in effect created by
  • 00:22:24
    the government, to purchase the
  • 00:22:27
    assets and rollover its STIP loan
  • 00:22:29
    into equity in the new company.
  • 00:22:31
    And again, the creditors got
  • 00:22:33
    the proceeds of that sale,
  • 00:22:35
    but they weren't
  • 00:22:36
    happy with the price that was paid.
  • 00:22:39
    And yet none of them, and no
  • 00:22:40
    one else, no other auto companies
  • 00:22:42
    showed up to pay a higher price.
  • 00:22:45
    >> So just to summarize, so you
  • 00:22:46
    think that if the bailout hadn't
  • 00:22:48
    happened, then in fact, General
  • 00:22:51
    Motors would have been liquidated?
  • 00:22:53
    >> I think it would have shut down.
  • 00:22:55
    And the question is, how expensive
  • 00:22:57
    would it have been to restart?
  • 00:23:00
    I mean, this was the analysis that
  • 00:23:01
    was being done in the Treasury
  • 00:23:02
    Department at the time.
  • 00:23:04
    How many other affected businesses
  • 00:23:06
    would shut down if GM shut down?
  • 00:23:07
    All of the car dealerships that
  • 00:23:09
    depended on GM, all of
  • 00:23:11
    the suppliers that depended on GM,
  • 00:23:13
    all of the auto body shops that
  • 00:23:15
    depended on parts from GM suppliers
  • 00:23:17
    who would have been shut down.
  • 00:23:20
    I can't remember the name of
  • 00:23:21
    the consulting firm in Detroit who
  • 00:23:23
    generally consults for
  • 00:23:25
    auto companies.
  • 00:23:26
    The estimate by that firm
  • 00:23:28
    whose name I forget at the time was
  • 00:23:30
    that had GM shut down,
  • 00:23:32
    3 million jobs would have also
  • 00:23:34
    stopped right then and there.
  • 00:23:36
    Because of the integrated supplier,
  • 00:23:39
    dealer, and customer networks that
  • 00:23:41
    depended on GM's operations.
  • 00:23:43
    And so from a macroeconomic point
  • 00:23:46
    of view, I think the government
  • 00:23:48
    rightly decided that in the middle
  • 00:23:50
    of this financial crisis to have
  • 00:23:53
    the largest American auto
  • 00:23:54
    manufacturer shut down,
  • 00:23:56
    with all of the attendant job
  • 00:23:58
    losses in the supplier and dealer
  • 00:24:01
    networks and service networks.
  • 00:24:04
    Would have made a bad situation
  • 00:24:06
    worse, and that the cost of
  • 00:24:08
    restarting all of those businesses
  • 00:24:10
    would have far exceeded any subsidy
  • 00:24:13
    that the government might otherwise
  • 00:24:16
    have had to convey to GM as part of
  • 00:24:18
    this process.
  • 00:24:20
    >> I mean,
  • 00:24:21
    Jim, the only thing I would say is
  • 00:24:23
    those numbers are ignoring a very
  • 00:24:26
    important thing, and
  • 00:24:28
    that is, cars need to be sold.
  • 00:24:30
    I mean, people buy car.
  • 00:24:31
    So the numbers assume that GM would
  • 00:24:34
    shut down and no other car
  • 00:24:36
    manufacturer would sell those cars,
  • 00:24:38
    that those cars just would never
  • 00:24:40
    get sold.
  • 00:24:42
    And I think that's probably
  • 00:24:43
    an exaggeration.
  • 00:24:45
    >> No, I can see that Ford and
  • 00:24:47
    Chrysler, well, not Chrysler, but
  • 00:24:49
    [LAUGH] Ford and Japanese and
  • 00:24:51
    European car manufacturers
  • 00:24:53
    would have tried to step in.
  • 00:24:55
    But the loss in productive capacity
  • 00:24:58
    across the supplier networks,
  • 00:25:00
    I mean, part of the analysis was
  • 00:25:03
    a few look at the suppliers to GM
  • 00:25:05
    of a given part.
  • 00:25:06
    They're also suppliers to Toyota,
  • 00:25:09
    and to Ford, and to Hyundai.
  • 00:25:12
    And so if that supplier shuts down,
  • 00:25:14
    the contagion effects on all of
  • 00:25:17
    the other auto industries might be
  • 00:25:20
    very difficult to contain.
  • 00:25:23
    So in effect, the so called bailout
  • 00:25:25
    of GM was actually a bailout of
  • 00:25:27
    the supplier network, and
  • 00:25:28
    of all of the other auto companies
  • 00:25:30
    manufacturing in the United States.
  • 00:25:33
    Because had the tier one suppliers
  • 00:25:35
    to GA who are also suppliers to
  • 00:25:37
    the rest of the industry shut down,
  • 00:25:40
    the rest of the industry
  • 00:25:42
    would've shut down.
  • 00:25:43
    So your premise that there might
  • 00:25:45
    have been someone to step in,
  • 00:25:47
    theoretically, yeah.
  • 00:25:50
    That GM's market share might have
  • 00:25:51
    been picked up from someone else,
  • 00:25:53
    but less.
  • 00:25:54
    The GM bankruptcy caused the rest
  • 00:25:56
    of the supplier base to shut down,
  • 00:25:57
    which causes the rest of
  • 00:25:58
    the industry to shut down.
  • 00:26:00
    So the conclusion was reached that
  • 00:26:02
    the loss of productive capacity and
  • 00:26:04
    the contagion effects of a GM
  • 00:26:06
    shutdown were far greater than any
  • 00:26:08
    subsidy that the government might
  • 00:26:11
    have had to convey to get
  • 00:26:12
    this all done.
  • 00:26:14
    Well, thank you very much.
  • 00:26:15
    >> Thanks so much, Jim.
  • 00:26:16
    >> Thanks for having me, guys.
  • 00:26:19
    >> Jules,
  • 00:26:19
    what the discussion really
  • 00:26:21
    highlighted is just how difficult
  • 00:26:24
    it is to make decisions in a crisis
  • 00:26:27
    situation like a GM bankruptcy.
  • 00:26:30
    Jules, there's so
  • 00:26:31
    many things that could happen and
  • 00:26:33
    there's so many contingencies.
  • 00:26:36
    It's a very difficult time for
  • 00:26:38
    the government to make decisions
  • 00:26:40
    like this.
  • 00:26:42
    >> Yeah, but Jonathan,
  • 00:26:43
    I also think it's important to not
  • 00:26:45
    make All Alse Equal mistakes
  • 00:26:47
    because those types of hypothetical
  • 00:26:49
    scenarios are particularly privy to
  • 00:26:51
    making all else equals mistakes.
  • 00:26:53
    Where you just say,
  • 00:26:54
    if we had done this differently,
  • 00:26:55
    this would have happened.
  • 00:26:57
    But we do need to take into
  • 00:26:58
    account, all the other parties that
  • 00:27:00
    are involved in the other decisions
  • 00:27:02
    that they would have made had we
  • 00:27:04
    done something differently.
  • 00:27:06
    And so that makes these
  • 00:27:07
    hypothetical scenarios so hard.
  • 00:27:09
    >> I agree.
  • 00:27:10
    It's essential not
  • 00:27:11
    to make the All Else Equal
  • 00:27:13
    mistake in those situations.
  • 00:27:16
    >> So next episode, we're going to
  • 00:27:18
    go back to our usual biweekly
  • 00:27:19
    schedule with a conversation about
  • 00:27:21
    labor contracts.
  • 00:27:22
    And we just saw in the discussion
  • 00:27:24
    about bankruptcy, how important
  • 00:27:26
    labor contracts can be and
  • 00:27:27
    how important it is that firms can
  • 00:27:29
    stick with labor contracts.
  • 00:27:31
    [MUSIC]
  • 00:27:32
    >> Thanks for listening to
  • 00:27:34
    All Else Equal podcast.
  • 00:27:36
    Please leave us a review at Apple
  • 00:27:38
    podcasts.
  • 00:27:39
    We love to hear from our listeners.
  • 00:27:42
    And be sure to catch our next
  • 00:27:43
    episode by subscribing or
  • 00:27:45
    following our show wherever you
  • 00:27:47
    listen to your podcasts.
  • 00:27:49
    For more information episode,
  • 00:27:51
    visit allelseequalpodcast.com or
  • 00:27:54
    follow us on LinkedIn.
  • 00:27:55
    The All Else Equal podcast is a
  • 00:27:57
    production of Stanford University's
  • 00:28:00
    Graduate School of Business, and
  • 00:28:02
    is produced by alumni FM.
  • 00:28:04
    [MUSIC]
Tags
  • Corporate bankruptcy
  • Debt restructuring
  • Business liquidation
  • General Motors bailout
  • Financial reorganization
  • Modigliani and Miller Proposition
  • Debt-equity ratio
  • Economic crisis management
  • Government intervention
  • Corporate finance