00:00:00
[MUSIC]
00:00:07
Hi, I'm Jonathan Burke, Professor
00:00:09
of Finance in the Graduate School
00:00:11
of Business at Stanford university.
00:00:13
>> And I'm Jules van Vincebergin,
00:00:15
a Finance Professor
00:00:16
at the Wharton School of
00:00:17
the University of Pennsylvania.
00:00:19
>> And this is
00:00:20
the All Else Equal Podcast.
00:00:24
Welcome back, everybody.
00:00:26
Before we get started today I just
00:00:27
want to make a call out to our
00:00:29
listeners and thank them for
00:00:30
listening, especially the listeners
00:00:32
who subscribed.
00:00:33
It's really amazing to see
00:00:35
how many subscribers they are and
00:00:37
it's really motivating in terms of
00:00:39
what we're doing here.
00:00:41
>> Today we're going to talk about
00:00:42
corporate bankruptcy.
00:00:44
And the All Else Equal
00:00:45
mistakes we're going to talk about
00:00:47
is the assumption that the act of
00:00:48
declaring bankruptcy itself is
00:00:50
precipitating the end of the firm.
00:00:53
That is, the bankruptcy decision
00:00:54
itself is consequent in ending
00:00:56
the firm's existence.
00:00:57
And I think that's a pretty common
00:00:58
assumption, Jonathan.
00:00:59
Usually when we see that a firm
00:01:01
declares bankruptcy people think,
00:01:02
that's the end of it.
00:01:04
>> Yeah, as seemingly
00:01:05
obvious as this assumption is,
00:01:07
it's a mistake, okay?
00:01:09
So let's think about that.
00:01:11
There are two reasons a firm would
00:01:12
enter bankruptcy.
00:01:13
One reason is the underlying
00:01:15
business is failing.
00:01:16
And so I think that happens when
00:01:18
the cost of continuing the business
00:01:20
is higher than what it actually
00:01:22
brings in in revenues.
00:01:23
>> Exactly.
00:01:24
>> Or alternatively, underlying
00:01:26
business is perfectly fine, but
00:01:28
the firm just has too much debt.
00:01:30
So one example that I think
00:01:31
is interesting to discuss
00:01:33
here is Hertz, right?
00:01:34
So Hertz doing the COVID
00:01:36
crisis had a pretty rough time, and
00:01:38
at some point they decided
00:01:39
to declare bankruptcy.
00:01:41
And then 12 months later,
00:01:43
suddenly Hertz has emerged
00:01:44
out of bankruptcy.
00:01:46
So I think that is a clear
00:01:47
indication that if we have to
00:01:49
choose between the two reasons for
00:01:50
bankruptcy, one was the business is
00:01:52
failing, the other one was they
00:01:53
just had too much debt and they had
00:01:55
to somehow reorganize that.
00:01:57
I think the second is the more
00:01:58
plausible explanation.
00:01:59
>> Well, but
00:02:00
the other thing to remember is,
00:02:02
even during the bankruptcy,
00:02:03
you could still rent Hertz cars.
00:02:05
In fact, from a consumer's
00:02:07
perspective, they didn't even
00:02:08
know about the bankruptcy.
00:02:09
Hertz looked just like Avis.
00:02:11
Why don't we talk about how
00:02:13
bankruptcy came to be?
00:02:14
Originally when you didn't pay your
00:02:16
debts back, they put you in prison,
00:02:18
and we as a society realized there
00:02:19
were some moral issues with that.
00:02:21
And so we came up with bankruptcy
00:02:23
law, which essentially was
00:02:25
a way for debtors to collect as
00:02:27
much as they could.
00:02:28
And obviously you can't put
00:02:29
a corporation in prison.
00:02:30
So in that sense,
00:02:32
corporate bankruptcy is just
00:02:34
an orderly process for the debtors
00:02:37
to collect as much as they can.
00:02:40
They're obviously not going to be
00:02:41
fully paid back, otherwise wouldn't
00:02:43
have a bankruptcy, but they're
00:02:44
going to get as much as they can.
00:02:45
>> And so the debt holders
00:02:46
have a very clear choice to make.
00:02:48
Whenever a firm is declaring
00:02:49
bankruptcy, given the fact that
00:02:51
the debt holders want to get back
00:02:53
as much as they can, how will they
00:02:55
get back as much as they can?
00:02:56
On the one hand they can say,
00:02:58
let's just sell off every piece
00:03:00
of property that Hertz has.
00:03:01
Let's sell off all the cars,
00:03:03
that sell off all the real estate,
00:03:04
and let's see how much money we
00:03:06
can recoup that way.
00:03:07
The alternative for the debt
00:03:09
holders is to say, you know what,
00:03:11
actually Hertz is worth more to us
00:03:13
by just continuing operating it and
00:03:15
try to recoup as much money as we
00:03:17
can that way, right.?
00:03:18
>> Right, so really what bankruptcy
00:03:21
is in a corporate situation is
00:03:23
simply a change of control.
00:03:25
Before the bankruptcy, the equity
00:03:28
holders controlled the firm, or the
00:03:30
shareholders controlled the firm.
00:03:33
After the bankruptcy,
00:03:34
the shareholders get nothing and
00:03:36
the debt holders get all their
00:03:38
assets, so they take control of
00:03:39
the firm and they make decision to
00:03:41
continue operations or
00:03:42
shut the firm down, but the debtors
00:03:44
will make that decision.
00:03:46
So anybody who has lent money to
00:03:48
the firm gets control of the firm.
00:03:50
So the really insightful thing to
00:03:53
realize is all
00:03:54
a corporate bankruptcy is is
00:03:57
a change of control.
00:03:58
>> So now let's generalize this
00:04:01
a bit and just think about two
00:04:02
identical firms.
00:04:05
The firms operate exactly the same
00:04:06
type of business,
00:04:07
they sell the same products,
00:04:08
they have the same employees,
00:04:10
everything is the same.
00:04:11
The only thing that's different
00:04:12
between these two firms is
00:04:14
how much debt they have.
00:04:15
Now the question is,
00:04:16
is the decision to continue
00:04:18
operating the business,
00:04:20
is that in any way dependent on how
00:04:22
much debt we have, okay?
00:04:24
>> Let's assume that the firm with
00:04:27
debt declares bankruptcy, but
00:04:30
assume the firm is healthy,
00:04:32
what's going to happen?
00:04:34
>> Well, in that case,
00:04:35
if the business model is fine, and
00:04:37
it's more profitable to continue
00:04:38
operating the firm compared to
00:04:40
shutting it down,
00:04:40
he'll just continue.
00:04:42
>> Now the all equity
00:04:42
firm obviously can't declare
00:04:44
bankruptcy because there's no debt
00:04:45
in that firm, but it's identical,
00:04:47
it will also continue operating.
00:04:49
So both firms will
00:04:50
continue operating.
00:04:51
Okay, let's take the alternative.
00:04:53
>> So now we're looking at a firm
00:04:55
where the cost of continuing
00:04:56
operation is higher than
00:04:57
the revenue would brings in.
00:04:59
So from a business decision making
00:05:01
point of view, the better decision
00:05:03
is to shut down the firm.
00:05:04
>> So when the debt holders take
00:05:06
possession of the firm,
00:05:07
what are they going to do?
00:05:09
They're going to
00:05:09
liquidate the firm.
00:05:11
But obviously the same must be true
00:05:13
of the all equity firm.
00:05:15
It's not a good business decision
00:05:17
of that firm to keep operating.
00:05:18
We just said,
00:05:19
you're better off shutting it
00:05:21
down than keep operating.
00:05:22
So the equity holders in that
00:05:24
firm will also shut it down.
00:05:26
And so yet again,
00:05:27
both firms make the same decision.
00:05:30
>> So we've just proven
00:05:31
the point where we started off
00:05:32
the discussion.
00:05:33
And that is the act of declaring
00:05:35
bankruptcy itself has no impact on
00:05:37
the question of whether it's a good
00:05:39
business decision to keep the firm
00:05:41
operating or not.
00:05:43
So now the question is,
00:05:44
can we generalize this argument if
00:05:46
the way that the firm is financed
00:05:47
with debt and equity and
00:05:49
in what ratio doesn't matter for
00:05:50
this important business decision,
00:05:52
does it matter for
00:05:53
any other business decision that
00:05:54
we're making inside the firm?
00:05:56
>> And the answer is no,
00:05:58
it doesn't matter,
00:05:59
using the same intuition.
00:06:01
Financial economists call this the
00:06:03
Modigliani and Miller Proposition,
00:06:05
named after Modigliani and
00:06:07
Miller, who won the Nobel Prize for
00:06:09
pointing it out.
00:06:10
Ironically, they were not the first
00:06:12
people to derive it.
00:06:13
The first person to
00:06:14
have this important
00:06:15
insight was John Burr Williams, and
00:06:18
I think the Nobel Prize Committee
00:06:20
erred in not giving the Nobel Prize
00:06:22
to John Burr Williams, when they
00:06:24
gave it to Modigliani Miller.
00:06:26
>> Isn't there some funny joke
00:06:27
about this, about propositions?
00:06:29
>> Yes, my good friend
00:06:31
Mark Rubinstein used to
00:06:32
say if a proposition is named
00:06:34
after somebody,
00:06:35
it almost certainly means they were
00:06:37
not the first people to derive it.
00:06:40
>> So let's use John Burr Williams'
00:06:41
argument to understand it better.
00:06:44
The way that he went about
00:06:45
it was as follows.
00:06:45
He said, suppose that there's only
00:06:48
one person who owns both the equity
00:06:50
and the debt of the firm.
00:06:53
Now what could it possibly matter
00:06:55
for the business decision how
00:06:57
to proceed in what ratio that
00:06:59
person holds both those pieces.
00:07:01
>> In other words, it's just
00:07:03
relabeling, that person has all
00:07:05
the cash flows the firm generates.
00:07:07
So you can label one as debt and
00:07:08
equity, but the total cash flows
00:07:10
are the same, and so
00:07:11
that person isn't going to care.
00:07:13
And that's how John Burr Williams
00:07:15
derived the very important insight
00:07:18
that how the firm finances itself
00:07:20
doesn't affect the underlying
00:07:23
business model of the firm.
00:07:25
>> And so there is a very important
00:07:27
all else equal mistake that follows
00:07:29
from this wrong way of thinking
00:07:31
about the debt equity ratio.
00:07:33
And that is that many people,
00:07:35
often bankers, claim that you
00:07:37
should always finance your firm
00:07:40
with debt because they say debt is
00:07:42
cheaper because she can get it at
00:07:44
a lower rate than having to entice
00:07:47
equity holders to invest with you.
00:07:49
And for that reason, you should
00:07:51
always finance your firm with debt.
00:07:53
>> And that's an all else equal
00:07:55
mistake because what it's ignoring
00:07:57
is the reason debt has a lower.
00:08:00
Return is because it's less risky.
00:08:02
Equity is more risky than debt and
00:08:04
has a higher return.
00:08:05
It's no cheaper,
00:08:06
it's just your investors are taking
00:08:08
on different risks.
00:08:10
>> And in fact, if as a firm you
00:08:12
take on more debts, you are
00:08:13
actually making the equity riskier.
00:08:16
Because you will have to pay
00:08:17
the debt holders back first before
00:08:19
the equity holders get anything.
00:08:20
>> Exactly, the equity of an all
00:08:22
equity firm is less risky than
00:08:24
the equity of a firm with debt.
00:08:26
But the overall riskiness of
00:08:28
the firm is the same and
00:08:30
Berwyn said that.
00:08:31
Look, if I have an all equity firm
00:08:33
that's going to have a certain
00:08:34
level of risk, if I'm the single
00:08:36
investor in that firm or if
00:08:38
I've a firm with debt and equity,
00:08:40
certainly my debt and equity is
00:08:41
going to have different risks.
00:08:43
But I'm getting the same cash flows
00:08:46
so my overall risk is the same as
00:08:48
it is for the all equity firm.
00:08:50
>> And now finally,
00:08:50
let's circle back to the very
00:08:52
beginning of our discussion.
00:08:53
In making the mistake of equating
00:08:55
bankruptcy with liquidation,
00:08:56
people often make the mistake of
00:08:58
subsidizing firms when there's no
00:09:00
reason for it.
00:09:01
We've heard a lot about when firms
00:09:03
get in trouble,
00:09:04
we need to bail them out.
00:09:06
But let's think a little carefully
00:09:08
about what that bailing out
00:09:09
actually implies.
00:09:11
>> Well, when would be a situation
00:09:12
where you've to bail out a firm?
00:09:13
Because as we discussed, if
00:09:15
the firm is a good firm to operate,
00:09:17
the debt holders will
00:09:18
keep operating it, so
00:09:20
there's no reason to bail it out.
00:09:22
So the only time you have to
00:09:23
bail it out is if the firm doesn't
00:09:25
make sense to operate.
00:09:26
And normally when we say we have
00:09:28
firms that don't make sense to
00:09:29
operate, the optimal thing is to
00:09:31
shut them down.
00:09:32
The only condition under which
00:09:34
you wouldn't want to shut the firm
00:09:36
down is there some externality for
00:09:38
the firm operating.
00:09:39
>> So for example, there could be
00:09:41
suppliers of the firm or
00:09:42
other parties that are connected to
00:09:44
the firm.
00:09:45
In the case of General Motors,
00:09:46
I think this argument was made
00:09:48
quite forcibly that too many people
00:09:50
dependent on General Motors to be
00:09:51
couldn't let it fail and the
00:09:53
externalities were large enough.
00:09:55
>> But the problem of course Jules
00:09:57
is, if I am the debt holder I would
00:09:59
like to subsidize.
00:10:00
I could easily argue that I'm going
00:10:03
to shut the firm down if
00:10:04
the subsidy didn't exist,
00:10:06
knowing full well that in fact that
00:10:08
wouldn't be my case.
00:10:10
So we have to be very careful when
00:10:12
debt holders announce or
00:10:13
threaten to shut the firm down.
00:10:15
We have to actually make sure that
00:10:17
that's what they're going to do.
00:10:18
>> Yeah, because anybody likes to
00:10:20
receive a subsidy if he can.
00:10:22
So Jonathan, one last thing to
00:10:24
discuss then though is, when
00:10:26
you look at the surveys of CFOs and
00:10:28
you ask CFOs what is the most
00:10:31
important part of your job?
00:10:33
They do indicate that how much debt
00:10:35
and equity financing they should
00:10:37
use is at the top of that list.
00:10:39
So what are we missing?
00:10:41
>> Well, I think this will we
00:10:42
talked about he was pretty
00:10:44
simplistic and
00:10:45
then in the real world
00:10:46
the decisions are more complicated.
00:10:49
We spoke about one
00:10:49
friction already,
00:10:51
which is the externalities, right?
00:10:53
The first kind of externalities,
00:10:54
but there are other
00:10:55
frictions because obviously
00:10:57
bankruptcies cost the process.
00:10:59
You have to hire lawyers, and
00:11:01
the other thing about bankruptcy is
00:11:03
contracts don't survive.
00:11:05
So not just the debt contract, you
00:11:06
could have other contracts in the
00:11:08
firm that don't survive bankruptcy.
00:11:09
So it could be difficult to
00:11:11
write contracts if the firm
00:11:13
has a lot of debt.
00:11:14
Because the person on the other
00:11:16
side of the contract anticipates if
00:11:17
there's a chance of bankruptcy and
00:11:19
this contract might not be honored.
00:11:21
>> Like the labor contract?
00:11:22
>> Exactly, there's a good example,
00:11:24
the labor contract.
00:11:25
So workers inferred in a lot of
00:11:27
debt might worry that a labor
00:11:28
contract that says they can't be
00:11:31
fired would be violated in the case
00:11:33
of bankruptcy.
00:11:34
>> And then there is another
00:11:35
very important friction and
00:11:37
that friction is, and we've
00:11:38
discussed this friction before.
00:11:40
Financing with debt has a benefit
00:11:42
because interest payments are tax
00:11:44
deductible.
00:11:44
Because your tax bill is computed
00:11:46
on the after interest payment
00:11:48
profits not the before interest
00:11:50
payment profits.
00:11:51
And so by financing your firm
00:11:53
more with debts,
00:11:54
you can keep more of the money for
00:11:56
the stakeholders in the firm and
00:11:58
not give it to the government.
00:12:00
And that increases the value of
00:12:01
the firm but also sometimes we call
00:12:03
the tax shield.
00:12:04
>> And that is one of my big
00:12:07
concerns about how we tax.
00:12:09
What effectively the government's
00:12:12
doing is encouraging firms to hold
00:12:14
more debt.
00:12:15
If the firm has more debt,
00:12:16
it's harder to write long-term
00:12:19
contracts.
00:12:19
So it's harder for the employees to
00:12:22
write a contract with a firm that
00:12:23
gives them job security.
00:12:25
Now, job security is a pretty
00:12:26
useful thing.
00:12:27
And we're moving risk
00:12:28
from the employee to the firm,
00:12:30
which is the optimal thing to do.
00:12:32
So making their contract harder to
00:12:35
write makes employees harder to
00:12:37
hire.
00:12:38
And it's overall bad I think for
00:12:40
the economy as a whole because
00:12:41
having that insurance is good for
00:12:43
everybody.
00:12:44
>> Agreed.
00:12:45
So let's summarize.
00:12:46
We started off with in a world
00:12:48
without these frictions that we
00:12:50
discussed at the end,
00:12:51
the trade off between how much debt
00:12:53
and equity you should hold,
00:12:55
there isn't much there.
00:12:57
It doesn't really matter how you
00:12:58
finance yourself whether it's with
00:12:59
equity or debt.
00:13:00
We illustrated this with a very
00:13:01
simple decision to make,
00:13:03
which was the decision to continue
00:13:05
operating or not.
00:13:06
And we concluded that for that
00:13:07
business decision it didn't matter
00:13:09
how you financed yourself and
00:13:10
came been generalized.
00:13:11
Adam came to the conclusion that
00:13:13
for any business decision in this
00:13:14
frictionless world, it wouldn't
00:13:16
matter how you financed yourself.
00:13:18
But to make it more nuanced at the
00:13:19
end, I do think we need to include
00:13:21
these frictions in the discussion.
00:13:23
How important are these frictions,
00:13:24
how important are these
00:13:25
labor contracts?
00:13:26
How valuable is the fact that debt
00:13:28
is text deductible, how costly is
00:13:30
the bankruptcy process for
00:13:31
everybody involved?
00:13:33
>> That's a very important
00:13:34
insight Jules.
00:13:35
In other words, it is important
00:13:37
when people claim that the level
00:13:40
of debt matters, that they also
00:13:42
explain what friction is causing it
00:13:45
to matter.
00:13:46
If they don't explain what
00:13:48
friction is causing it to matter,
00:13:49
I'm highly suspicious that in fact
00:13:51
they want to get something out of
00:13:52
you and they're going to make
00:13:54
a blecious argument to do that.
00:13:55
>> And just saying the rate of
00:13:57
return on debt is lower than
00:13:58
the rate you have to pay to equity
00:14:00
holders to entice them to invest,
00:14:02
that argument on its own doesn't
00:14:04
specify friction, and for
00:14:05
that reason is not a useful
00:14:07
argument to use.
00:14:08
>> Okay, Jules, so I think now it's
00:14:09
time to introduce our guest.
00:14:11
>> We're very happy to have our
00:14:13
guest today, Jim Millstein.
00:14:15
Jim is the Co-Chairman of
00:14:17
Guggenheim Securities, investment
00:14:18
banking in capital markets business
00:14:20
of Guggenheim Partners, a global
00:14:22
investment and advisory firm.
00:14:23
From 2009 to 2011, Jim was
00:14:25
the Chief Restructuring Officer at
00:14:27
the US Department of the Treasury
00:14:29
when the Obama administration
00:14:31
bailed out General Motors.
00:14:32
In that role he was also
00:14:34
responsible for oversight and
00:14:35
management of the department's
00:14:37
largest investments
00:14:38
in the financial sector and was
00:14:40
the principal architect of AIG's
00:14:41
restructuring and recapitalization.
00:14:44
Prior to joining the treasury,
00:14:45
Jim served as Global Co-Head of
00:14:47
Corporate Restructuring at
00:14:48
Lazard from 2000 to 2008.
00:14:50
An authority represented the United
00:14:52
Auto Workers in connection with the
00:14:54
restructuring of their contractual
00:14:57
relations with GM, Ford,
00:14:58
and Chrysler from 2005 to 2007.
00:15:01
Jim welcome to the show.
00:15:03
>> Nice to be here, thanks for
00:15:04
having me.
00:15:05
>> So Jim you spent your whole
00:15:07
career dealing with firms in
00:15:09
bankruptcy.
00:15:10
Let me ask you a question
00:15:11
just as a summary of all
00:15:12
the bankruptcies you've dealt with.
00:15:14
What fraction of the time was
00:15:16
the end result liquidation versus
00:15:18
a transfer of control?
00:15:20
>> I've probably worked on 400
00:15:21
different restructurings over
00:15:23
the course of the last 42 years
00:15:25
doing this kind of work.
00:15:26
And I would say really only twice
00:15:29
over that period has it resulted in
00:15:32
a liquidation.
00:15:34
The chapter 11 of
00:15:35
the United States Bankruptcy Code
00:15:37
was really designed to facilitate
00:15:39
the reorganization of companies
00:15:40
rather than their liquidation.
00:15:42
Liquidation value to use legally
00:15:45
as a standard by which plans of
00:15:48
reorganization are judged.
00:15:50
But it is a very rare bankruptcy
00:15:52
that ends up liquidated.
00:15:54
>> So Jim, obviously the transfer
00:15:56
of control from equity holders to
00:15:58
debt holders is not simple,
00:16:00
it involve costs.
00:16:01
What do you think the major costs
00:16:03
are and how important are they in
00:16:06
the bigger picture
00:16:07
of the company as a whole?
00:16:09
>> Well, the friction costs of all
00:16:11
the professionals involved in
00:16:13
a large case,
00:16:14
those can be quite considerable.
00:16:16
But the bankruptcy courts,
00:16:17
the judges themselves have gotten
00:16:19
relatively good at policing
00:16:21
the running up of
00:16:22
unnecessary fees and expenses.
00:16:24
But the truth is that in a large
00:16:27
bankruptcy, all of the parties
00:16:30
retain specialized advisors.
00:16:32
And so you can have a conference
00:16:35
goal or a court hearing or
00:16:36
a negotiation session.
00:16:38
And when you look around,
00:16:40
there are 100 people billing their
00:16:43
time to a creditor,
00:16:44
or in many cases,
00:16:45
to the estate itself.
00:16:47
And so those friction costs
00:16:49
are real.
00:16:51
>> Okay, the costs are substantial
00:16:53
in absolute terms.
00:16:54
But in relative terms versus
00:16:55
the value of the corporation,
00:16:57
it's still not more than in
00:16:59
the percentage terms.
00:17:00
One, two, three,
00:17:01
four percent of the value of
00:17:03
the corporation of all the costs
00:17:05
associated with the bankruptcy, or
00:17:07
am I wrong about that?
00:17:08
>> It's very hard to give a rule of
00:17:11
thumb.
00:17:12
There are cases such as the Caesars
00:17:14
bankruptcy on which I worked where
00:17:17
the professional fees were running
00:17:19
a couple of $100 million a year.
00:17:22
But at the end of the day,
00:17:24
the estate, the reorganized company
00:17:26
was worth $30 billion.
00:17:28
So would you pay $200 million
00:17:30
to right size the balance sheet of
00:17:32
a company that ultimately was worth
00:17:34
$30 billion?
00:17:35
Yeah, you would.
00:17:37
Would you pay $3 million to right
00:17:39
size the balance sheet of a company
00:17:42
ultimately worth $50 million?
00:17:44
You'd be very careful in
00:17:46
supervising the professionals
00:17:49
involved in that size of case to
00:17:51
keep the fees down.
00:17:54
>> So, Jim, on that note,
00:17:55
do you think the bankruptcy process
00:17:57
is the most efficient way to handle
00:18:00
financial distress?
00:18:01
Or do you think there's
00:18:02
a lot of room for improvement?
00:18:04
>> Look, there's always room for
00:18:05
improvement.
00:18:06
I sat on a commission organized by
00:18:08
the American Bankruptcy Institute
00:18:09
called at the Commission to
00:18:11
Study Reform of Chapter 11.
00:18:12
And we came up with probably a 400
00:18:14
page tome that had a series
00:18:16
of recommendations to improve
00:18:18
the process.
00:18:19
But when you compare the legal
00:18:21
framework for
00:18:21
reorganizations applicable iin
00:18:24
the United States to those
00:18:25
available in other jurisdictions,
00:18:27
really Chapter 11 is probably
00:18:29
the most efficient reorganization
00:18:32
statute in the world.
00:18:33
Indeed, over the course of my
00:18:35
career over the last 40 years,
00:18:38
all of the so-called developed
00:18:40
countries and
00:18:41
many of the developing countries
00:18:43
have modernized their bankruptcy
00:18:46
statutes really after Chapter 11.
00:18:49
Because it has been
00:18:50
such a successful form in
00:18:52
which to salvage the valuable bits
00:18:55
of an operating business and
00:18:57
allow it to reorganize.
00:18:59
>> Could you comment a bit on
00:19:01
how you view bailouts?
00:19:02
So, for example,
00:19:03
the General Motors bankruptcy,
00:19:05
I think a lot of academics viewed
00:19:07
that as a watershed event in
00:19:08
the sense that the government
00:19:10
bailed out General Motors.
00:19:12
But absent that government support,
00:19:14
don't you think the company would
00:19:15
have been reorganized anyway?
00:19:17
>> Actually, I think most people
00:19:19
who are not bankruptcy
00:19:20
professionals don't understand what
00:19:23
happened in the GM bankruptcy.
00:19:25
The government really behaved
00:19:27
like an aggressive activist vulture
00:19:30
fund, and it employed tactics very
00:19:32
similar to those that the most
00:19:34
sophisticated investors
00:19:36
in Chapter 11 employ to facilitate
00:19:38
the reorganization of the company.
00:19:40
Do I think GM would have
00:19:41
survived without
00:19:42
the government's intervention?
00:19:44
Not at that time,
00:19:45
it had a severe run on
00:19:46
the liquidity available to it, and
00:19:49
it would have had to shut down.
00:19:51
Now, one of the reasons I think
00:19:53
most people don't understand and
00:19:56
unfairly criticized the government
00:19:58
and its capacity a dip lender in
00:20:01
that proceeding is that
00:20:02
the government went to the existing
00:20:05
secured creditors of GM,
00:20:07
the people first in line to receive
00:20:09
the value of GM's assets.
00:20:11
And said,
00:20:12
hey, if you guys want to put up
00:20:15
the dip, if you want to finance
00:20:17
it in Chapter 11,
00:20:19
please go right ahead.
00:20:21
And it was only after those
00:20:23
creditors who really were entitled
00:20:25
to whatever the value of GM was
00:20:27
because they had liens on virtually
00:20:30
all of its assets.
00:20:31
It was only after those creditors
00:20:33
declined the offer to
00:20:35
provide financing.
00:20:37
Now, remember,
00:20:38
when this all occurred,
00:20:39
this was in January of 2009,
00:20:41
in the middle, probably the deepest
00:20:44
point in the financial crisis.
00:20:45
And in the same way that
00:20:47
the federal government was a lender
00:20:49
of last resort through the fed,
00:20:51
through the FDIC,
00:20:52
through the Treasury Department to
00:20:55
the financial industry.
00:20:56
It turned out that the most
00:20:58
sophisticated distressed and
00:21:00
special situation investors who
00:21:02
had piled into GM secured debt were
00:21:04
unwilling to step up at that
00:21:06
moment of crisis and keep GM alive.
00:21:08
And so in order to save the jobs,
00:21:10
in order to keep the factories
00:21:12
running, in order to ensure that
00:21:14
the largest domestic automobile
00:21:16
manufacturer didn't shut down in
00:21:19
the middle of the crisis,
00:21:20
the government was forced
00:21:22
to step in where private investors
00:21:24
refused to tread.
00:21:26
>> How do you know those investors
00:21:28
weren't even more sophisticated,
00:21:31
knowing full well that the Obama
00:21:33
administration wasn't going to let
00:21:36
GM fail?
00:21:37
And so they didn't
00:21:38
provide the financing because
00:21:40
they anticipated the bailout.
00:21:43
>> Yes, well, the reason academics
00:21:45
have swirled around this and tried
00:21:48
to comment on it is because those
00:21:50
investors made a huge stink when
00:21:52
the government then after becoming
00:21:55
the dip lender sought to get the
00:21:57
company quickly out of bankruptcy.
00:22:00
As many of them would have done in
00:22:02
a similar position had they made
00:22:05
the dip loan.
00:22:06
Because a company as complex as
00:22:08
GM with international operations, I
00:22:11
mean, really very complicated, very
00:22:14
hard to run international company
00:22:16
in one bankruptcy jurisdiction.
00:22:19
So GM's assets were sold as a going
00:22:21
concern to a newly formed entity,
00:22:23
in effect created by
00:22:24
the government, to purchase the
00:22:27
assets and rollover its STIP loan
00:22:29
into equity in the new company.
00:22:31
And again, the creditors got
00:22:33
the proceeds of that sale,
00:22:35
but they weren't
00:22:36
happy with the price that was paid.
00:22:39
And yet none of them, and no
00:22:40
one else, no other auto companies
00:22:42
showed up to pay a higher price.
00:22:45
>> So just to summarize, so you
00:22:46
think that if the bailout hadn't
00:22:48
happened, then in fact, General
00:22:51
Motors would have been liquidated?
00:22:53
>> I think it would have shut down.
00:22:55
And the question is, how expensive
00:22:57
would it have been to restart?
00:23:00
I mean, this was the analysis that
00:23:01
was being done in the Treasury
00:23:02
Department at the time.
00:23:04
How many other affected businesses
00:23:06
would shut down if GM shut down?
00:23:07
All of the car dealerships that
00:23:09
depended on GM, all of
00:23:11
the suppliers that depended on GM,
00:23:13
all of the auto body shops that
00:23:15
depended on parts from GM suppliers
00:23:17
who would have been shut down.
00:23:20
I can't remember the name of
00:23:21
the consulting firm in Detroit who
00:23:23
generally consults for
00:23:25
auto companies.
00:23:26
The estimate by that firm
00:23:28
whose name I forget at the time was
00:23:30
that had GM shut down,
00:23:32
3 million jobs would have also
00:23:34
stopped right then and there.
00:23:36
Because of the integrated supplier,
00:23:39
dealer, and customer networks that
00:23:41
depended on GM's operations.
00:23:43
And so from a macroeconomic point
00:23:46
of view, I think the government
00:23:48
rightly decided that in the middle
00:23:50
of this financial crisis to have
00:23:53
the largest American auto
00:23:54
manufacturer shut down,
00:23:56
with all of the attendant job
00:23:58
losses in the supplier and dealer
00:24:01
networks and service networks.
00:24:04
Would have made a bad situation
00:24:06
worse, and that the cost of
00:24:08
restarting all of those businesses
00:24:10
would have far exceeded any subsidy
00:24:13
that the government might otherwise
00:24:16
have had to convey to GM as part of
00:24:18
this process.
00:24:20
>> I mean,
00:24:21
Jim, the only thing I would say is
00:24:23
those numbers are ignoring a very
00:24:26
important thing, and
00:24:28
that is, cars need to be sold.
00:24:30
I mean, people buy car.
00:24:31
So the numbers assume that GM would
00:24:34
shut down and no other car
00:24:36
manufacturer would sell those cars,
00:24:38
that those cars just would never
00:24:40
get sold.
00:24:42
And I think that's probably
00:24:43
an exaggeration.
00:24:45
>> No, I can see that Ford and
00:24:47
Chrysler, well, not Chrysler, but
00:24:49
[LAUGH] Ford and Japanese and
00:24:51
European car manufacturers
00:24:53
would have tried to step in.
00:24:55
But the loss in productive capacity
00:24:58
across the supplier networks,
00:25:00
I mean, part of the analysis was
00:25:03
a few look at the suppliers to GM
00:25:05
of a given part.
00:25:06
They're also suppliers to Toyota,
00:25:09
and to Ford, and to Hyundai.
00:25:12
And so if that supplier shuts down,
00:25:14
the contagion effects on all of
00:25:17
the other auto industries might be
00:25:20
very difficult to contain.
00:25:23
So in effect, the so called bailout
00:25:25
of GM was actually a bailout of
00:25:27
the supplier network, and
00:25:28
of all of the other auto companies
00:25:30
manufacturing in the United States.
00:25:33
Because had the tier one suppliers
00:25:35
to GA who are also suppliers to
00:25:37
the rest of the industry shut down,
00:25:40
the rest of the industry
00:25:42
would've shut down.
00:25:43
So your premise that there might
00:25:45
have been someone to step in,
00:25:47
theoretically, yeah.
00:25:50
That GM's market share might have
00:25:51
been picked up from someone else,
00:25:53
but less.
00:25:54
The GM bankruptcy caused the rest
00:25:56
of the supplier base to shut down,
00:25:57
which causes the rest of
00:25:58
the industry to shut down.
00:26:00
So the conclusion was reached that
00:26:02
the loss of productive capacity and
00:26:04
the contagion effects of a GM
00:26:06
shutdown were far greater than any
00:26:08
subsidy that the government might
00:26:11
have had to convey to get
00:26:12
this all done.
00:26:14
Well, thank you very much.
00:26:15
>> Thanks so much, Jim.
00:26:16
>> Thanks for having me, guys.
00:26:19
>> Jules,
00:26:19
what the discussion really
00:26:21
highlighted is just how difficult
00:26:24
it is to make decisions in a crisis
00:26:27
situation like a GM bankruptcy.
00:26:30
Jules, there's so
00:26:31
many things that could happen and
00:26:33
there's so many contingencies.
00:26:36
It's a very difficult time for
00:26:38
the government to make decisions
00:26:40
like this.
00:26:42
>> Yeah, but Jonathan,
00:26:43
I also think it's important to not
00:26:45
make All Alse Equal mistakes
00:26:47
because those types of hypothetical
00:26:49
scenarios are particularly privy to
00:26:51
making all else equals mistakes.
00:26:53
Where you just say,
00:26:54
if we had done this differently,
00:26:55
this would have happened.
00:26:57
But we do need to take into
00:26:58
account, all the other parties that
00:27:00
are involved in the other decisions
00:27:02
that they would have made had we
00:27:04
done something differently.
00:27:06
And so that makes these
00:27:07
hypothetical scenarios so hard.
00:27:09
>> I agree.
00:27:10
It's essential not
00:27:11
to make the All Else Equal
00:27:13
mistake in those situations.
00:27:16
>> So next episode, we're going to
00:27:18
go back to our usual biweekly
00:27:19
schedule with a conversation about
00:27:21
labor contracts.
00:27:22
And we just saw in the discussion
00:27:24
about bankruptcy, how important
00:27:26
labor contracts can be and
00:27:27
how important it is that firms can
00:27:29
stick with labor contracts.
00:27:31
[MUSIC]
00:27:32
>> Thanks for listening to
00:27:34
All Else Equal podcast.
00:27:36
Please leave us a review at Apple
00:27:38
podcasts.
00:27:39
We love to hear from our listeners.
00:27:42
And be sure to catch our next
00:27:43
episode by subscribing or
00:27:45
following our show wherever you
00:27:47
listen to your podcasts.
00:27:49
For more information episode,
00:27:51
visit allelseequalpodcast.com or
00:27:54
follow us on LinkedIn.
00:27:55
The All Else Equal podcast is a
00:27:57
production of Stanford University's
00:28:00
Graduate School of Business, and
00:28:02
is produced by alumni FM.
00:28:04
[MUSIC]