00:00:00
Translator: Sebastian Betti
Reviewer: Gisela Giardino
00:00:14
I have good news and bad news for you.
00:00:18
The good news is that in the future
we all will need to work fewer hours.
00:00:22
The bad news --
00:00:24
(Applause)
00:00:26
We started with the right foot.
00:00:28
(Applause)
00:00:29
The bad news is that in the future
we will have fewer jobs.
00:00:37
30 years ago,
when I was studying engineering,
00:00:39
my first two jobs were amazing,
00:00:42
were drawing soil resistance curves
00:00:45
in a soil mechanics firm,
00:00:47
and counting doors and windows
on a large architecture plan
00:00:51
in a construction company.
00:00:53
Today those two jobs no longer exist;
00:00:56
or, rather, they exist
but are done by a computer.
00:01:00
I'm not a futurist guru.
00:01:01
I can't tell you what the jobs
of the future will look like.
00:01:05
I wish I could, having
so many students with us today.
00:01:07
But what I can tell you
is that those jobs
00:01:10
will not be the ones we have now,
00:01:14
and they will be fewer.
00:01:17
If I could put myself in the guru's shoes
00:01:20
to tell you something about the future,
00:01:22
I would probably tell you
that I see two divergent timelines,
00:01:26
two futures.
00:01:27
One future of abundance
00:01:30
in which technology teaches us
to produce more with less resources,
00:01:33
including less work,
00:01:36
and in which we are all wealthier,
00:01:38
not only in material objects
but also in time,
00:01:41
in our power to choose
what to do with our lives.
00:01:46
I also see another future, kind of
the negative of the future of abundance:
00:01:50
a future where technology
replace the worker
00:01:54
and inequality continues to grow.
00:01:55
A future with many spectators
but a few protagonists.
00:02:02
Which of these two futures
do you think is the most likely?
00:02:07
Today no one denies that
technology substitutes labor.
00:02:10
First, the more routine and
mechanical tasks, for instance,
00:02:14
the ATM replaces the cashier;
00:02:17
the email replaces the postman;
smartphone apps replace the secretary.
00:02:22
And this is just the tip of the iceberg,
00:02:24
because many more jobs are substituted
in the production line:
00:02:27
weavers, technical operators, cobblers;
00:02:30
the list is long.
00:02:32
And, if at the beginning the most
"human," "handmade" occupations
00:02:36
are protected,
00:02:38
the machine learns
and shortens the distance.
00:02:42
And we already have online
translators and accountants,
00:02:46
robots that cook and deliver,
00:02:49
programs that diagnose diseases,
write the news
00:02:54
and manage investment funds.
00:02:58
And we all are in the line of fire,
in principle.
00:03:01
In fact, a recent World Bank study
00:03:03
that looked into the issue
00:03:05
of technological substitution
in the Latin American neighborhood
00:03:08
found that, for Argentina,
00:03:10
60 percent of present jobs
were exposed to automation.
00:03:13
60 percent of our jobs
will soon be competing
00:03:17
with a machine or a program.
00:03:22
Now, if a machine can do for ARS 5
what I can do for ARS 10,
00:03:28
I have two options:
00:03:31
work for ARS 5, that is,
for half of the income
00:03:36
or leave my job to the machine.
00:03:39
This implies that, if left alone,
00:03:42
technological progress generates
ill-distributed abundance.
00:03:47
It produces a lot for very few.
00:03:50
Because although
it increases productivity,
00:03:53
so that we produce more with less,
00:03:56
these productivity gains raise
the income of the owner of the machine,
00:03:59
the robot, the program,
the remaining worker.
00:04:03
It does so at the expense of the income
of the rest of the workers,
00:04:07
who work for less, or do not work.
00:04:11
And that's only the beginning
of this timeline.
00:04:14
An old anecdote, apocryphal
as usually anecdotes are,
00:04:18
tells us that Henry Ford II, then
the owner of the automaker Ford,
00:04:22
invited Walter Reuther,
the historic leader
00:04:26
of the American auto workers' union,
00:04:28
to visit his recently automated factory.
00:04:32
At the end of the walk, Ford stopped,
put a hand on Reuther's shoulder and said,
00:04:37
with a dose of sarcasm
and pointing at the machines:
00:04:39
"Walter, I am worried
about how you are going
00:04:42
to get these new 'workers'
to pay the union dues?"
00:04:48
Reuther, unmoved, answered:
00:04:51
"What worries me, Henry,
is how you're going to get them
00:04:55
to buy your cars."
00:04:58
Let's take this anecdote to the extreme:
00:05:00
let's imagine a world where
all the goods and services are produced
00:05:04
by machines, robots and programs
owned by the 1 percent of the population,
00:05:08
the "Henry Fords of this world."
00:05:11
The natural question is:
If the remaining 99 percent
00:05:17
work for less or are unemployed,
00:05:20
who consumes what these machines produce?
00:05:23
Now, if no one consumes,
what do the machines produce for?
00:05:28
What’s the point
of technological progress?
00:05:32
Economists have long known
00:05:34
that the rich consume
a smaller share of their income.
00:05:37
The intuition is fairly simple:
00:05:38
As they have everything, they satiate.
00:05:42
And they save: for retirement,
for the children, the legacy, for power.
00:05:48
Then what happens?
00:05:49
If income concentrates in a few rich,
consumption drops.
00:05:53
And if consumption drops,
00:05:55
the economy not only
becomes more unequal;
00:05:58
it stagnates.
00:06:01
And technological progress takes
a pause. And everyone loses.
00:06:07
I know what you are thinking.
00:06:12
"It's Saturday! Enough downers!"
00:06:14
(Laughter)
00:06:15
"Where is that 'TEDx moment'
00:06:17
that makes us laugh and moves us
to reconcile with our lives?"
00:06:21
Well, I have good news
and bad news for you.
00:06:25
The bad news is that this is not
that kind of TEDx talk.
00:06:28
(Laughter)
00:06:29
The good ones, as we said at the
beginning, another future is possible.
00:06:36
Almost 100 years ago,
00:06:39
more precisely in 1930,
00:06:41
the British economist John Maynard Keynes
00:06:43
imagined the future of his grandchildren;
00:06:47
that is, more or less our present.
00:06:51
Like us now, it foreshadowed that the
machines, the increase in productivity,
00:06:56
technological progress would generate
lots of goods with little work.
00:07:01
But, in addition, he also predicted
00:07:03
that we would all work 15 hours a week
00:07:06
and would devote the rest
of our time to creative leisure,
00:07:10
aesthetic appreciation
- Keynes was an aesthete -
00:07:13
or to come here to the TEDx talks.
00:07:17
In principle, it makes sense.
00:07:19
In fact, when I mentioned this
00:07:21
at the beginning of the talk,
several of you
00:07:23
probably thought: "Less work,
what can be better than that?"
00:07:26
If we worked fewer hours,
we created many more individual jobs,
00:07:30
everybody has at least some work,
everybody is happy.
00:07:33
What we would label the "leisure society"
in the new sociology.
00:07:39
What's missing in this rationale?
00:07:42
Imagine that tomorrow at work
we tell our boss:
00:07:45
"Starting today I will work
four hours a week instead of eight --
00:07:50
or a day, rather.
00:07:53
Just do the maths.
00:07:55
Most likely, our boss would say:
00:07:57
"Starting today, you will be paid
about half your wage."
00:08:03
What does this mean?
00:08:04
That, if we reduce work hours,
00:08:06
we distribute the remaining working hours
among more workers.
00:08:09
If everybody work fewer hours,
there are more jobs.
00:08:11
But this at the expense that each
individual worker receives less income;
00:08:15
unless the owner of the machines,
the robots, the programs,
00:08:19
unilaterally, spontaneously,
00:08:21
chooses to distribute
his own income among his workers
00:08:24
an outcome that, a priori,
looks rather improbable.
00:08:29
Reducing working hours only
distributes scarcity;
00:08:32
but it does not alter
00:08:34
the way income is shared between
workers and capitalists.
00:08:39
In this light, the distance,
the bridge that goes
00:08:44
from the future of inequality
and stagnation
00:08:46
to the future of shared prosperity,
to the Keynesian utopia,
00:08:49
essentially requires
that we learn how to distribute
00:08:53
the fruits of technology progress.
00:08:54
And the good news is
that this bridge exists,
00:08:58
and it borrows an idea that is
at once old and innovative:
00:09:02
a universal basic income.
00:09:07
What is it?
00:09:10
In a nutshell, it would be a monthly
sum of money on behalf of the State,
00:09:15
that complements the income
00:09:19
from a job of fewer hours and less salary.
00:09:23
Defined in this way, it sounds
suspiciously simple, but it is not.
00:09:26
For starters, it costs money.
00:09:31
True, we can think that,
00:09:32
if technology makes the owner
of the machine richer,
00:09:35
this would lead them to pay more taxes,
00:09:38
which would ultimately be used
to pay for a universal income.
00:09:42
At any rate, if we want to fund
a universal income scheme
00:09:46
we need to collect taxes
in a different way,
00:09:48
we need a more progressive tax system.
00:09:53
And that's not the only problem.
00:09:56
A universal income opens some
delicate moral dilemmas, for instance,
00:10:01
should it be paid only to those
who have a registered job,
00:10:04
as a reward and incentive to the effort,
00:10:08
or to everyone, even to those
who never intended to work?
00:10:14
In the first case, we would be
excluding informal workers
00:10:18
that cannot verify their jobs.
00:10:20
And we would also be excluding
00:10:22
volunteers in soup kitchens,
workers in the social economy;
00:10:26
and homeworkers,
housewives and househusbands.
00:10:31
In the second case,
the one independent of having a job,
00:10:34
we would include all of above,
00:10:36
as well as all the poets,
authors, vocational athletes.
00:10:41
And yes, also bums and hooligans.
Everyone.
00:10:46
What would be fairer? Everyone or
only those who have a formal job?
00:10:50
And what do we talk about when
we talk about work in this context?
00:10:55
Frankly, I do not know
which option is the best.
00:10:57
And that does not worry too much,
00:10:59
because no option is perfect,
00:11:03
given the reasons I've just explained.
00:11:06
And, besides, this debate has just begun.
00:11:08
What I do know is that,
00:11:09
whatever the variety of universal income
00:11:12
that we choose to promote,
00:11:13
Argentina is in a privileged position
to move forward with this idea.
00:11:17
For many reasons,
both positive and negative.
00:11:21
On the negative side,
we have an employment problem.
00:11:25
Also, our workforce,
00:11:27
our current and future workers,
00:11:31
are mostly from a background --
00:11:33
low- and medium-skilled,
00:11:37
precisely the ones most exposed
to technological substitution.
00:11:42
And we don't have a lot of
technology yet, let's be honest,
00:11:45
we haven't imported
much technology so far.
00:11:47
When this process starts in earnest,
it'll hit us harder than other countries.
00:11:51
Hence, the 60 percent
of the World Bank study.
00:11:55
But there is also positive reasons.
00:11:57
Among them, perhaps the most important
is that we are not that far away.
00:12:02
We have universal child allowance
and universal pension,
00:12:06
and family allowances
and unemployment insurance.
00:12:10
Universal income would be
the natural continuity of a decade
00:12:14
in which we learn how to raise
our standard of social protection.
00:12:19
Argentina is, more than many other
countries, including many developed ones,
00:12:23
better prepared culturally
to embrace this idea.
00:12:29
The idea has several advantages.
00:12:31
For example, from an economic standpoint,
00:12:34
it draws an almost perfect circle.
00:12:36
Simply note that what we are doing
00:12:37
is using part of the dividends
from technological progress,
00:12:41
transferring this resources via taxes
00:12:43
to workers, whose demand,
whose consumption is essential
00:12:47
to sustain technological progress.
00:12:49
But also, and I believe more importantly,
00:12:52
universal income responds
to a moral problem:
00:12:56
What's the use of technological progress
if it creates abundance
00:13:01
that concentrates in the few hands
who already have everything?
00:13:07
(Applause)
00:13:16
I know that many of you may think
that this idea is premature,
00:13:21
or even delirious.
00:13:23
To address these concerns, it is always
useful to resort to History.
00:13:27
For example, in 1889 German Chancellor
Otto von Bismarck introduced
00:13:34
the pension system and
was labelled a "socialist."
00:13:38
The word "socialist"
is today innocuous, but back then
00:13:41
and for a hard-core conservative
like Bismarck was a serious insult.
00:13:45
"Communism" was marginal in those days,
otherwise they would have called him that.
00:13:49
And the same happened when U.S. President
Franklin Roosevelt attempted to create
00:13:52
the pension system in 1935,
00:13:56
in the midst of economic depression.
00:13:57
Even in the face of a depression
the pension of old age was resisted.
00:14:01
Well, universal income
is as "delirious" today
00:14:04
as the pension system
was just 100 years ago.
00:14:09
Nor is it delusional to think
00:14:11
of turning technological
progress into leisure time.
00:14:15
In fact, if we resort
once more to History,
00:14:18
the technical revolution
of the late 19th century,
00:14:21
reduced the average weekly hours worked
in developed countries from 70 to 45.
00:14:28
In the coming decades,
00:14:29
technological progress could cut
that average by half,
00:14:33
if combined with a universal income.
00:14:36
We said at the beginning:
00:14:38
The good news is that in the future
we will work fewer hours;
00:14:41
the bad news is that in the future
we will have fewer jobs.
00:14:44
The universal income offers a bridge
00:14:47
to cross from the bad future
to the good future,
00:14:51
a bridge to share prosperity.
00:14:55
It does not eliminate the option to work,
00:14:57
so important to many of us;
00:15:00
it gives us the option of time.
00:15:04
"The government should guarantee
a minimum universal income
00:15:09
funded by taxes."
00:15:11
How much do you agree
or disagree with this?
00:15:15
This is what we asked
a few weeks ago to 500 people,
00:15:21
on an online survey we run with the help
of Mariano Sigman and Guillermo Solovey.
00:15:27
The answers, naturally, varied a lot
with the ideological preferences,
00:15:30
a theme that could take
another TEDx talk.
00:15:33
For this talk, the relevant result
is the following:
00:15:36
more than half of the respondents,
specifically 77 percent --
00:15:41
with varying degrees of agreement,
supported that proposition,
00:15:46
that universal income funded with taxes.
00:15:48
Now I am asking you:
00:15:50
A universal income funded with taxes.
00:15:53
How much do you agree
or disagree with this?
00:15:57
You don't need to answer right away.
Think about it.
00:16:01
Think about all the pros and cons
that I mentioned.
00:16:03
Take your time,
talk it over with friends.
00:16:07
There's still time.
00:16:09
For now, this is just a delirious idea
for an uncertain future.
00:16:16
For now.
00:16:18
Thank you.
00:16:19
(Applause)